Contracts
can be, and are often deliberately designed to be incomplete. This is because
there is a trade-off between the present costs of drafting a more complete
agreement and the later inefficiencies stemming from the absence of exhaustive
arrangements. Hence, environmental complexities that increase the costs of
contract drafting can be expected to lead to lower completeness of the most
efficient contracts, while more exhaustive contracts can be expected to be
drafted only under conditions of increased potential for later inefficiencies. Consequently,
the degree of contractual completeness is a product of an attempt by the
parties involved to minimize the net economic costs of contractual exchange
(Crocker & Reynolds, 1993).
Defense procurement normally involves
high, reoccurring investments into relationship-specific assets provided by a
relatively small group of highly specialized contractors. Moreover, due to extensive
lead times and costs of development and production of major weapons systems,
the government ends up being tied to particular contractors once the contract
is signed and the work begins (Crocker
& Reynolds, 1993). Consequently, there is a high administrative burden
on the government, which involves the selection, governance and compensation of
multiple private contractors. As a result, detailed procurement regulations
have been developed to substantially reduce this burden. These regulations list
the duties of the contracting parties, as well as the methods of conflict
resolution between them; and provide the structure for the design of
permissible contractual agreements (Crocker
& Reynolds, 1993). Consequently, the governmental contractual officers
are expected to take environmental factors into account and following the
relevant regulations select the most appropriate contract from among the
alternative forms open to them, subject to more senior approval. In spite of
this considerable amount of regulations, the various forms of contract which
can be chosen by the contractual officers from among the alternatives, allow
them to choose contracts with various levels of completeness (Crocker & Reynolds, 1993).
Contractual compensation is
particularly sensitive to the degree of completeness inherent in the contract
which outlines it. The most restrictive and complete contract in this respect,
is the “firm-price” contract, which sets a fixed price and declares that this
fixed price will remain unchanged irrespective of future events (Crocker & Reynolds, 1993). Other types
of contracts allow the price to fluctuate to various degrees due to possible
future events, and thus carry various degrees of risk of future difficulties, if
the future event does not fall neatly into any of the categories outlined in
the contract. The most flexible and the least complete contract of this type is
the one which allows for the periodic negotiation of nonbinding target prices (Crocker & Reynolds, 1993).
References
Crocker, K. J. and Reynolds, K. J. (1993). The efficiency of
incomplete contracts: An empirical analysis of air force engine procurement. The RAND Journal of Economics, 24(1),
126-146.
No comments:
Post a Comment