At its simplest, national defense can definitely be considered a pure
public good if its benefits to citizens are both nonexcludable and nonrival.
If no citizen can be excluded from the benefits of a certain good once that
good is provided, then the benefits of that good are nonexcludable. Usually the benefits of a good are nonexcludable
whenever it is prohibitively expensive to exclude anyone from enjoying those
benefits. When the consumption of the benefits of a certain good by one
individual in no way diminishes the amount available for consumption to other
individuals, the benefits of that good are said to be nonrival (Stiglitz, 1988).
National defense, however, serves at least two functions. At one level,
the defense forces are created in order to repel any attack by another country.
And at another level, the presence of a powerful defense force can deter an
attack by another country from happening in the first place.
Whenever national defense deters attacks on the country from occurring,
it definitely functions as a pure public good, as, first, no citizen can be
excluded from enjoying these benefits, and second, the consumption of the
benefits of a deterred attack by one citizen, will not in any way reduce the
amount of these benefits available for consumption to other citizens (Kennedy,
1975, p. 43).
However, when an attack on the country does take place and the national
defense forces get mobilized to repel it; national defense clearly ceases to be
a pure public good. There are several related reasons for this. When a country
is attacked, one area of the country may end up consuming defense resources at
the expense of another area; making the benefits of national defense subject to
rivalry between different parts of the country (Kennedy, 1975, p. 43).
Moreover, the military establishment always has plans and estimates regarding
which parts of the country are more strategically valuable. Consequently,
during an attack, the military may very well decide to abandon some parts of
the country to the enemy in order to focus on defending these more
strategically valuable locations. This, in effect, makes some parts of the
country excludable from the benefits of national defense in the event of war
(Kennedy, 1975, p. 43).
However, according to Herman Kahn (2007, p. 180) the military which, in
the event of an attack on its country, plans to abandon certain parts of the
country in order to defend more strategic sectors and/or allow one section of
the country to consume defense resources at the expense of another, is greatly
undermining a valuable objective of defense: deterrence; especially if this is
a country with a relatively small military force, such as Canada. In
particular, since there are great advantages to striking first, the defense
force of a small military power that will be left after this first attack can
be expected to be quite small (Kahn, 2007, p. 180). Consequently, a plan which
under such conditions calls for focusing the remaining defense forces on trying
to terminate the war by attacking the enemy’s offense, while trying to limit
the damage, is unsound; as it will lead the potential enemy to believe that,
should he attack, he’ll get away with almost no harm to his country. So not
surprisingly, such a plan would greatly reduce the deterrent role of the armed
forces of a country preparing to being attacked. Consequently, according to Kahn
(2007, p. 180), the plans of the military should call for ordering the small
remaining force to attack the population and industry of the enemy’s country.
Such a plan would remind the potential enemy that in the event of him
undertaking an attack, his country will sustain considerable damage even if his
attack manages to destroy the main part of the targeted country’s defense force;
so he’ll be more likely to be deterred from attacking. Consequently, if Kahn is
correct, the military establishment of a small military power, which, in the
case of an enemy attack, plans on focusing its remaining forces on attacking
the enemy’s population and industry, has, quite possibly, turned national
defense into a public good even for the case of a defensive war.
References
Kahn, H. (2007). On Thermonuclear War.
New Brunswick (U.S.A.): Transaction Publishers.
Kennedy, G. (1975). The Economics
of Defence. London: Faber and Faber.
Stiglitz, J. E. (1988). Economics of
the Public Sector. 2nd ed. New York: Norton.
No comments:
Post a Comment